Australian National Accounts: Input-Output Tables

This is not the latest release View the latest release

Input–Output (I-O) tables provide detailed information about the supply and use of products in the Australian economy

Reference period
2016-17 financial year
Released
27/06/2019

Main features

Input–Output (I–O) tables are part of the Australian national accounts, complementing the quarterly and annual series of national income, expenditure and product aggregates. They provide detailed information about the supply and use of products in the Australian economy, and the structure of and inter–relationships between Australian industries.

This publication contains the Input–Output tables for 2016–17. The tables presented here are the basic transaction tables, coefficients, industry flow, margins tables, and product and industry concordances.

With the release of tables for 2016–17, the ABS has completed 30 Input–Output tables for Australia. Previous tables were for 1958–59, 1962–63, 1968–69, 1974–75, 1977–78 to 1983–84, 1986–87, 1989–90, 1992–93 to 1994–95, 1996–97, 1998–99, 2001–02, 2004–05 to 2009–10, and 2012-13 to 2015-16.

A list of the 2016–17 Input–Output tables available in this release can be accessed by clicking the Data downloads section.

For further information about these and related statistics, contact the National Information and Referral Service on 1300 135 070.

Input-Output multipliers

Overview

The ABS frequently receives requests from users who are seeking updated Input–Output (I–O) multipliers. The ABS has not published I–O multipliers since the 1998–99 issue of our product Australian National Accounts: Input–Output Tables (cat. no. 5209.0.55.001) and does not plan to compile and reissue this table. As such, the ABS is unable to support user requests for assistance with multipliers.

Production of multipliers was discontinued with the 2001–02 issue for several reasons. There was considerable debate in the user community as to their suitability for the purposes to which they were most commonly applied, that is, to produce measures of the size and impact of a particular project to support bids for industry assistance of various forms.

Limitations of Input–Output multipliers for economic impact assessment

I–O multipliers are most commonly used to quantify the economic impacts (both direct and indirect) relating to policies and projects. While their ease of use makes I–O multipliers a popular tool for economic impact analysis, they are based on limiting assumptions that results in multipliers being a biased estimator of the benefits or costs of a project.

Inherent shortcomings and limitations of multipliers for economic impact analysis include:

  • Lack of supply–side constraints: The most significant limitation of economic impact analysis using multipliers is the implicit assumption that the economy has no supply–side constraints. That is, it is assumed that extra output can be produced in one area without taking resources away from other activities, thus overstating economic impacts. The actual impact is likely to be dependent on the extent to which the economy is operating at or near capacity.
  • Fixed prices: Constraints on the availability of inputs, such as skilled labour, require prices to act as a rationing device. In assessments using multipliers, where factors of production are assumed to be limitless, this rationing response is assumed not to occur. Prices are assumed to be unaffected by policy and any crowding out effects are not captured.
  • Fixed ratios for intermediate inputs and production: Economic impact analysis using multipliers implicitly assumes that there is a fixed input structure in each industry and fixed ratios for production. As such, impact analysis using multipliers can be seen to describe average effects, not marginal effects. For example, increased demand for a product is assumed to imply an equal increase in production for that product. In reality, however, it may be more efficient to increase imports or divert some exports to local consumption rather than increasing local production by the full amount;
  • No allowance for purchasers’ marginal responses to change: Economic impact analysis using multipliers assumes that households consume goods and services in exact proportions to their initial budget shares. For example, the household budget share of some goods might increase as household income increases. This equally applies to industrial consumption of intermediate inputs and factors of production.
  • Absence of budget constraints: Assessments of economic impacts using multipliers that consider consumption induced effects (type two multipliers) implicitly assume that household and government consumption is not subject to budget constraints.
  • Not applicable for small regions: Multipliers that have been calculated from the national I–O table are not appropriate for use in economic impact analysis of projects in small regions. For small regions multipliers tend to be smaller than national multipliers since their inter–industry linkages are normally relatively shallow. Inter–industry linkages tend to be shallow in small regions since they usually don’t have the capacity to produce the wide range of goods used for inputs and consumption, instead importing a large proportion of these goods from other regions.
     

Concluding remarks

I–O multipliers represent one particular derived or modelled view of I–O data that goes beyond the publishing of the core I–O tables. In light of this, the ABS no longer produces multipliers as an extension of our I–O tables. Instead, users of the I–O tables can compile their own multipliers as they see fit, using their own methods and assumptions to suit their own needs from the data supplied in the main I–O tables.

While I–O multipliers may be useful as summary statistics to assist in understanding the degree to which an industry is integrated into the economy, their inherent shortcomings make them inappropriate for economic impact analysis. These shortcomings mean that I–O multipliers are likely to significantly over–state the impacts of projects or events. More complex methodologies, such as those inherent in computable general equilibrium (CGE) models, are required to overcome these shortcomings.

References

Show all

Alternative view of Input-Output tables

An alternative view of the 2016–17 Input-Output Tables (cat. no. 5209.0.55.001) has been produced to support the needs of users who apply the data in large and sophisticated models.

The variation relates to the treatment of imports data. In the Input-Output release for 2016–17 it offsets the treatment of freight and insurance services provided on imports by residents. These are already part of domestic output and should not be treated as imports, therefore in the main tables imports of freight and insurance services are adjusted downwards at an aggregated level.

While conceptually correct and in line with international standards, this adjustment can generate negative values for imports of transport services for certain industry groups which, being an accounting entry, have no economic meaning. These adjustments were included in previous Input-Output tables, but depending on data for individual years, imported services of water and air transport may more than compensate for the negative adjustment for a particular industry group, thus avoiding negatives appearing in the columns of Table 3 (Imports).

In the alternative view these negatives have been removed by adding the value of freight and insurance on imports provided by residents back into imports and, to maintain the balance on the current account, adding a similar value to exports. The value of this adjustment in 2016–17 is $1 425m.

The alternative view is available on request from the National Information and Referral Service on 1300 135 070 or email national.accounts@abs.gov.au.

Data downloads

Table 1. Australian production by product group by industry

Table 2. Input by industry and final use category and imports by product group

Table 3. Imports - supply by product group and inputs by industry and final use category

Table 4. Reconciliation of flows at basic prices and at purchasers' prices by product group

Table 5. Industry by industry flow table (direct allocation of imports)

Table 6. Direct requirement coefficients (direct allocation of imports)

Table 7. Total requirement coefficients (direct allocation of imports)

Table 8. Industry by industry flow table (indirect allocation of imports)

Table 9. Direct requirement coefficients (indirect allocation of imports)

Table 10. Total requirement coefficients (indirect allocation of imports)

Table 17. Primary input content (total requirements) per $100 of final use by industry

Table 19. Specialisation and coverage ratios by industry

Table 21. Composition of supply of products containing margins

Table 23. Wholesale margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 24. Retail margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 25. Restaurants, hotels and clubs margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 26. Road transport margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 27. Rail transport margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 28. Pipeline transport margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 29. Water transport margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 30. Air transport margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 31. Port handling margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 32. Marine insurance margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 33. Gas margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 34. Electricity margin on supply by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 35. Net taxes on products by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 36. Goods and services tax on products by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 37. Duty on products by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 38. Taxes on products nei by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 39. Subsidies on products by product group by using industry and final use category

Table 40. Industry and product concordances

History of changes

Show all

Back to top of the page